Hermann Weyl, tax accountant

It’s tax time for Usaians. I’ve been plodding through the thick book of forms and instructions, tips and cautions, tables and worksheets and schedules and Paperwork Reduction Act notices. The unwelcome annual ritual always reminds me of the words of Hermann Weyl:

Our federal income tax law defines the tax y to be paid in terms of the income x; it does so in a clumsy enough way by pasting several linear functions together, each valid in another interval or bracket of income. An archeologist who, five thousand years from now, shall unearth some of our income tax returns together with relics of engineering works and mathematical books, will probably date them a couple of centuries earlier, certainly before Galileo and Vieta.

We should forgive Weyl his peevish tone; Form 1040 can put anyone in a grumpy mood. And maybe he had a point. The tax code has changed in many ways since Weyl gave his contemptuous assessment in 1940, but after all these years the income tax is still defined by a piecewise linear function. Here are the current rates for single taxpayers:

2006 single tax rate chart

Graphically, the tax y as a function of taxable income x looks like this:

piecewise linear tax function

A few notes on this income-tax function:

  • It is a proper function in the mathematical sense of that term: Every income x ≥ 0 is mapped to a unique tax y.
  • The range of the function excludes negative incomes. In the real world, it’s quite possible to finish the year with a loss, but in tax land we are instructed: “Subtract line 42 from line 41. If line 42 is more than line 41, enter -0-.”
  • The function touches the origin (zero income means zero tax) and is monotonically increasing. There is no income level where you can earn more money and pay less tax.
  • The function is concave upward, which implies that the tax is progressive: People with higher incomes pay a higher proportion of their income as tax. But the progression stops at 35 percent: As x approaches infinity, the ratio y/x approaches a limiting value of 0.35.
  • As a function defined by “pasting together” several straight-line segments, it is continuous but not differentiable at the points where the segments meet.

Weyl’s complaint against the tax code might have had something to do with the last of these observations—the jaggedness of the curve, or the discontinuity of the first derivative—but I don’t think that gets to the heart of the matter. No one really cares whether or not the tax curve is twice differentiable. What bothered Weyl, I suspect, was the mere fact that the tax function is defined as a concatenation of segments. He wanted a curve defined by a single expression that could be evaluated in the same way throughout the range of the function. (By the way, does this concept have a name, other than “not piecewise”? Should we call it a piecefoolish function?)

In setting out to create such a function, an obvious approach is fitting a polynomial to the half-dozen points given in the tax-rate table. But this process is not quite as easy and straightforward as it might seem. A major problem is that there are really seven points in the table rather than six. The 35-percent bracket continues indefinitely, extending to arbitrarily large incomes, and so there’s really an additional point on the curve, somewhere out there where x = ∞ and y = 0.35x. If you ignore this extra point, the 35-percent bracket disappears entirely. If you try to place the point at infinity, its influence on a least-squares fit will overwhelm all the other points. I don’t know a good solution to this problem, so I’ve adopted an arbitrary one. Noting that the lengths of the tax brackets are roughly in geometric proportion, I’ve placed a seventh point at a position that maintains this approximate relation, x = 750,000, y = 242,360.50.

Let’s begin with a linear (i.e., first-degree) polynomial model of the tax brackets. Some people call this a “flat tax,” although that term seems to me more appropriate for a scheme in which everyone pays the same amount of tax; here, it means everyone pays at the same rate, or the same proportion of income. In any case, I don’t think the flat-tax fans would be enthusiastic about this flat tax:

graph of a linear fit to tax brackets

Following this formula, everyone with a taxable income below about $19,000 pays a negative tax, or in other words receives a subsidy from the government. For those with zero income, the subsidy is more than $6,000. Meanwhile, all those above the $19,000 threshold pay 32.6 percent of their income as tax.

A quadratic fit to the tax-table data looks slightly less inflamatory:

graph of quadratic fit to tax table

There’s still a bit of negative income tax, but it doesn’t kick in until income falls below $9,500, and the maximum subsidy is about $2,500. Overall, the curve is really quite a close fit to the data, with an r2 value of 0.9995. The largest residual error between the fitted curve and the data is $2,484, at the zero-income point. Perhaps one could use these linear and quadratic approximations to the tax-rate data to argue that the shape of the tax function “wants” to include a negative tax for the lowest incomes, but the official curve has been artificially cut off to prevent this. (The Earned Income Credit does allow some low-income taxpayers to have an effective negative tax, but the structure of the credit is different from that of the models discussed here. The EIC provides almost no benefit at zero income; the maximum negative tax is at an income of between $6,000 and $16,000.)

We can match the data points in the tax table as closely as we please simply by going to higher-degree polynomials, but this is not necessarily a good idea. A sixth-degree polynomial will thread itself through all seven of the specified points:

sixth-degree polynomial fit of tax-rate data

In between the specified points, the curve has some suspicious-looking lumps and sags. People earning about $250,000 seem to be getting a break, and those with incomes of $350,000 are paying a penalty. On taking a step back and looking at a broader range of incomes, the curve turns out to be far more bizarre:

graph of sixth-degree polynomial extrapolation

This is a tax function that Vice President Cheney might well appreciate. The Cheney family has reported that they had taxable income of $1.6 million last year; according to the sixth-degree polynomial, they should be due a refund—a negative income tax—of a little over $2 billion. Meanwhile, poor George W. Bush, who reported a meagre $642,905 of taxable income, is unlucky enough to find himself near the peak of that big hump in the curve. He would be asked to pay a tax of more than $1.5 million—almost three times his total earnings.

So maybe fitting a curve to the existing tax structure is not such a good idea after all. Let’s try to construct a curve that’s similar in overall form to the present tax brackets but not so rigidly constrained by the data in the table. The curve in the graph below is a quadratic that passes through three of the bracket-defining points, {0, 0}, {30650, 4220} and {336550, 97653}:

three-point quadratic-fit curve

Over the range of incomes shown, the shape of the curve is a reasonable match (at least by eye) to the piecewise tax function of the Internal Revenue Service. By construction, the function yields a zero tax for zero income and is positive everywhere else. It is concave upward. But there’s still a big problem:

quadratic fit to three points, extrapolation

The quadratic curve was constructed from data in the range between zero and a few hundred thousand dollars; outside that range, the function is free to go wild. In this case the slope of the curve becomes greater than 1 at about x = $1.8 million; beyond that income level, the tax rate is greater than 100 percent, so that the tax owed exceeds earnings. Even those of us who ardently want to soak the rich will have to admit that collecting such taxes might be difficult.

It begins to seem that Weyl’s request for a simple tax function is not so easy to satisfy. We can have a piecewise definition and make it do anything we want, but that is what Weyl was trying to get away from. We can have a flat tax, given by a first-degree polynomial, but many people think that would be socially and economically undesireable. With a polynomial of any degree higher than 1, the tax will eventually diverge either to +∞ or –∞.

On the other hand, we have certainly not exhausted the list of candidate functions. How about this one: y = xx1–ε, where ε is some positive number less than 1? Here’s what the tax curve looks like for ε = 0.027.

graph of y=x-x^(1-epsilon)

This is a fairly good match to the existing tax function over the range of x shown, and it doesn’t blow up at larger values of x. As x goes to infinity, y/x very slowly approaches 1 from below. (The tax rate reaches 90 percent for incomes above about 1037 dollars.) The function is concave upward, and it’s positive for all positive x.

In this formula the expression x1–ε could be replaced by any slowly growing function of x. An appealing candidate is log(x), but getting a sensible tax curve out of a logarithmic function is a bit of a chore. The first problem appears at the origin: log(x) diverges to negative infinity as x approaches zero from above, and so a small income will earn you an arbitrarily large negative tax. We can avoid the problem by working with log(x+1). A further difficulty is that log(x) grows so very slowly that over any wide range of incomes, y = x – log(x) doesn’t differ appreciably from y = x. The closest I’ve been able to come to an acceptable tax function is 0.335 x – 973 log(x + 1) + 1578:

graphxminuslogx

Here the tax is negative for any income below about $25,000.

The function xx/log(x), shown below, is somewhat better-behaved, although again fudge factors are needed to avoid singularities near the origin. (The actual equation being graphed here is –7.706(x+1)/log(x+2) + 0.893x – 2.297.)

graph of f(x) = x/log(x)

The mention of x/log(x) leads to a further thought, and a final fantasy. The function x/log(x) is well known as an approximation to pi(x), the function that counts the number of primes less than x. I think Weyl might have been pleased if the instructions to Form 1040 required you to enumerate the prime numbers up to your income level. This innovation would at last bring the federal tax code out of the age of Galileo and Viete, all the way up to Gauss and Riemann.

This entry was posted in mathematics, modern life.

6 Responses to Hermann Weyl, tax accountant

  1. Barry Cipra says:

    You say: “The [income-tax] function … is monotonically increasing. There is no income level where you can earn more money and pay less tax.” There is one other related property: The *after-tax* function, A(x) = x - T(x), is also monotonically increasing. That is, there should presumably always be some incentive to work harder and thereby earn more money. In fact, the current tax code violates this property by setting income thresholds above which certain tax credits or deductions are disallowed - there are cases where a one-dollar increase in income triggers a tax obligation increase of hundreds of dollars, creating a discontinuous nosedive in the after-tax function. This actually happened to me a couple of years ago when I had to advise my son to quit his summer job before his income exceeded the level at which I could still claim him as a dependent. He missed out on about a hundred dollars income, but between federal and state taxes, the deduction was worth nearly a thousand. (We had a lively debate over who that money belonged to. He thought he should be paid for quitting his job to stay home and play computer games. I thought otherwise.)

    As for terminology, the best name for “not piecewise” is probably “analytic.”

  2. randomwalker says:

    @Barry: I think the kind of logical inconsistency you point out is one of the real problems with the tax code, far more than the minor inconvenience of computing a piecewise linear function (especially since we have software to automate it.)

    There’s also the cognitive load: we have to evaluate how each little financial decision we take will affect our taxes and this leads to a lot of distress. That’s on top of the distress involved in actually doing your taxes.

  3. brian says:

    Re: “analytic.” The concept I’m trying to put my finger on is not really about the properties of the function but about the syntax of the definition. I want a name for the class of function definitions that don’t involve case analysis, or, as Weyl put it, “pasting … functions together, each valid in another interval….” I can see how every analytic function could be defined in this nonpiecewise way, but does the converse hold? If a function is defined in one piece, is it necessarily analytic? What about f(x) = |x|?

  4. Barry Cipra says:

    Re: “If a function is defined in one piece, is it necessarily analytic? What about f(x) = |x|?” It depends on how you define “defined”…. If you allow f(x)=|x| as a one-piece definition, then you can get any piecewise linear function with breaks at points x1, x2, x3,…, xn in one fell swoop in the form

    f(x) = a0 + b0x + b1|x-x1| + b2|x-x2| + b3|x-x3| + … + bn|x-xn|

    where the coefficients a0, b0, b1,…, bn are computed from the same sort of straightforward linear algebra that lets you find a polynomial of degree n that passes through n+1 given data points. (I’ll let you puzzle over why there are n+2 coefficients for what seems to be only n data points in the piecewise linear case.) It might be amusing to compute these coefficients for the IRS tax table. I still doubt Weyl would care for the resulting formula, though!

  5. Jess Austin says:

    It has been some time since I examined these matters, but I’m sure that at least some of the flat-tax proposals involved expansions of the earned-income tax credit, and so really were not adverse to a “negative tax”. However, the EITC in such a proposal probably wouldn’t be a near-linear monotonic continuation of the overall tax curve, as that would have bad effects on incentives.

    Incidentally, if Form 1040 annoys you with its obfuscation of the actually quite simple expressions used in taxation, don’t look at Part IV and Schedule AI of Form 2210, which are used to calculate underpayments and penalties for payers with varying income and withholding. It took me over an hour to figure out that I owed a penalty of $6. I consoled myself with the intuition that if I hadn’t filled out those sections of the form my penalty would have been hundreds more.

  6. I just started in a CPA firm, and I am trying to get a grip on health insurance, life insurance, and HSA’s, and when they are deductible or exempt on the 1040. Also, does anyone know of any books that might be of assistance being a beginner tax accountant.
    Thanks -Evan

    Also, I have made a blog website: http://beginnertaxaccountant.blogspot.com

    I am a beginner, the only one of the blog right now, so it is pretty worthless. Hoping to get people on there, if any one wants on or has any advice for me, including to telling me I do not have a clue what I am doing, feel free,